DEVELOPMENT,
TRADE EXPANSION, AND U.S. AGRICULTURE:
POLICIES
FOR THE 21ST CENTURY
Report
of the
Working
Group on International Trade and Development
Robert Paarlberg
Working Group Chair
Professor
Wellesley College
John Becker
USAID/LAC
State Department
Frank Fender
FAS/USDA
Office of International Cooperation
Earl Kellogg
Senior Vice President
Winrock International
Stephen Lewis
President
Carleton College
Mark Lindenberg
CARE
Gary Martin
Farmland Industries, Inc.
Edwin Price
Texas A & M University
Barbara Spangler
American Farm Bureau Federation
James Starkey
Senior Vice President
Universal Corporation
Ann Tutwiler
Central Soya Company
Norm Uphoff
Professor
Cornell University
Bryant Wadsworth
U. S. Meat Export Federation
Kelley White, Jr.
Economic Research Service
USDA
Marcia Will
Wilmer, Cutler & Pickering
John G. Stovall
Executive Director of the Commission on International
Trade, Development and Cooperation
National
Center for Food and Agricultural Policy
February
1997
PREFACE
This is one of three reports issued by
the National Center for Food and Agricultural Policy in connection with the
Commission on International Trade, Development and Cooperation. Another report
comes from the Working Group on International Agricultural Research and another
reports the Conclusions and Recommendations of the Commission.
This Working Group on International Trade
and Development was formed to assist the Commission by identifying the key
policy issues and offering background information and policy options. The
Commission�s report draws heavily on this report and adopts its major
recommendations.
The idea for this Commission grew out of
the debate that led up to the 1996 Farm Bill. A number of participants lamented
that the debate centered around a rather narrow set of policy issues, ignoring
some that were extremely critical to the long-term economic health of the U.S.
food and agricultural sector. Those neglected issues related to the stake U.S.
agriculture has in this country�s international affairs, and particularly our
economic interests in developing countries and emerging market economies.
There was a time when the agricultural
community was content to leave those lofty and far away matters to others. There
were more pressing problems closer to home. But not any more. Now that we are
integrated into the international economy, the connection is obvious: Economic
growth, trade liberalization, and stability in the so-called Third World are
just as important, if not more so, to the economic well being of U.S.
agriculture as the provisions of traditional domestic farm policy.
On behalf of the National Center for Food
and Agricultural Policy and the Commission, I wish to thank the members and
alternates who served on this working group. Special thanks are due Dr. Robert
Paarlberg, chair of the working group, for his leadership and for producing
this report.
Recognition and thanks are also due those
whose financial contributions made this all possible. They include: The
Economic Research Service; the Foreign Agricultural Service and the
Agricultural Research Service; USDA; USAID; Cargill, Inc.; DowElanco; Farmland
Industries; Pioneer Hi-Bred International; and Harvest States Cooperatives.
They deserve our thanks but bear no responsibility for the content of the three
reports and do not necessarily agree with their conclusions and
recommendations.
John G. Stovall
Senior Fellow
National Center for Food and Agricultural
Policy
TABLE OF CONTENTS
Preface��������������������������������������������������������������������������������� ���������������������������������������������������������������
I.������������� Statement
of Purpose: Development,
��������������� Trade
Expansion, and U.S. Agriculture �������������������������������������������������������������������
II.����������� The
Globalization of U.S. Agriculture������� ��������������������������������������������������������������
III.���������� U.S.
Assistance Policy in the Past: A
��������������� Success
or a Failure?�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������
IV.���������� Does
U.S. Assistance to Foreign Agricultural
��������������� Production
Hurt or Help U.S. Agriculture?�������������������������������������������������������������
V.����������� The
New Challenge in Development Cooperation��������������������������������
VI.���������� The
New Challenge in Trade���������������������������������������������������������������������������������������
VII.�������� Responding
to the Development Challenge:
��������������� Improving
Delivery Systems�����������������������������������������������������������������������������������������
������������������������������� Closer
Partnerships���������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������
������������������������������� Reduced
Micromanagement from Congress��������������������������������������������
������������������������������� Reduced
Dictation from the Foreign Policy
����������������������������������������������� Community��������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������
VIII.������� Institutional
Change: Long Term and
��������������� Short
Term Goals�����������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������
IX.���������� Opportunities
to Move Toward Partnership�����������������������������������������������������������
������������������������������� Multilateral
Agencies�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������
������������������������������� Other
U.S. Government Agencies,
����������������������������������������������� Including
State Governments�������������������������������������������������������
������������������������������� Reasons
to Partner with Foreign
����������������������������������������������� Governments�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������
������������������������������� Reasons
to Partner with PVOs
����������������������������������������������� and
Universities�����������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������
������������������������������� Reasons
to Partner with Private
����������������������������������������������� Investors�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������
X.����������� Parallel
Trade Policy Responses���������������������������������������������������������������������������������
XI.���������� Conclusion�����������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������
References����������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������
���������������
DEVELOPMENT,
TRADE EXPANSION, AND U.S. AGRICULTURE:
POLICIES
FOR THE 21ST CENTURY
Report
Of The Working Group On International Trade And Development
Robert
Paarlberg, Chair
I. Statement of Purpose: Development,
Trade Expansion, and U.S. Agriculture
The purpose of this Working Group has
been to envision, document, and describe new ways in which U.S. agriculture can
profit from revitalized trade and development cooperation policies abroad. In
world agriculture, doing good abroad and doing well at home can go
hand-in-hand. Abroad, we seek agricultural and rural development, which is
broadly-based and environmentally sustainable, and capable of improving food
security and economic welfare in developing countries. At home, we seek a U.S.
farm sector made more prosperous through continued growth in international
trade. To pursue these goals side-by-side, we envision new forms of cooperative
action among private-sector firms, private-voluntary organizations (PVOs) and
universities, as well as government agencies. Developing new partnerships
between the public and private sectors will be the key to success.
These new partnerships must:
��������������� Recognize the important role of
public sector investments at federal, state, and local levels, in building
physical infrastructure; developing education, health and research
institutions; and providing sound policies, regulatory, governance, and legal
systems.
��������������� Support and facilitate the
involvement of the private sector in developing efficient and robust
production, input/output marketing and international trade systems.
��������������� Give farmers, farm industries,
and consumers improved choices through greater access to open international
trade.
��������������� Support the involvement of PVOs,
in reaching and including local people in developing innovative solutions to
development and humanitarian problems.
��������������� Support and facilitate the
involvement of universities - including students, faculty, and extension
services - in education, research, and public service activities related to
agricultural development and trade.
This Working Group believes that broadly
based agricultural development efforts focused on benefiting developing
countries and people will also benefit the U.S., including U.S. agriculture.
The partnerships we recommend here are an affordable path to a better future
for farmers, farm communities, and agricultural industries in rich and poor
countries alike, and represent a worthy policy agenda for the U.S. agricultural
and international affairs community.
II. The Globalization of U.S. Agriculture
American agriculture has a strong
interest in the international development and trade policies of the U.S.
government. This is because the American agricultural sector is already one of
the most globalized sectors of the U.S. economy.
Total U.S. agricultural exports for 1995
were valued at $55.8 billion, or roughly one-tenth of total U.S. exports,
one-quarter of all agricultural exports world wide, and roughly 27 percent of
total U.S. gross farm income. Roughly 60 percent of new sales growth has been
occurring in developing countries. These agricultural exports stimulated an
additional $76.6 billion in economic activity across all sectors of the U.S.
economy in 1995, for a total economic boost of $132 billion. Roughly 17,300
U.S. jobs are now being created for every $1 billion in agricultural exports,
and roughly four-fifths of these export-linked jobs are created off the farm,
in upstream or downstream agricultural industries.
The dependence of the American
agricultural sector on exports will increase in the years ahead, because it is
demand abroad that has more room to grow. Population growth rates at home will
be low and consumption will have limited room to expand because income is
already relatively high. In the developing world, by contrast, population is
still growing rapidly and incomes are now in a position to grow rapidly as
well, from low levels. This portends a further enrichment of diets, leading to
added consumption of animal protein (meat, milk, eggs), boosting demand for
products (including animal feed products, such as corn and soybeans) which U.S.
agriculture is well equipped to produce and export. One USDA forecast projects
that between 1993 and 2010 the share of U.S. grain production that goes abroad
will increase from 16.4 percent to 28.6 percent. If income can be pushed to
grow above trend in these developing countries, even more will be exported. In
fact, USDA calculations reveal that higher income growth in developing
countries will be even more important than higher income growth at home in
stimulating future demand for U.S. grains (Gehlhar, Shane, and White 1996).
Without continued international trade
expansion driven by rapid economic growth in non-industrial and industrializing
countries, those who work in American agriculture will face a future burdened
by difficult adjustments. Productivity growth in American agriculture is so
high that without market expansion beyond our borders, more agricultural
workers at home (on the farm and off the farm) would have to move out of the
sector, a painful adjustment that would lower incomes for many, and, in some
cases, threaten the survival of entire farm and agribusiness-based rural
communities.
More than just the welfare of American
agriculture is at stake, of course. An expansion of U.S. farm exports driven
forward by broadly-based international income gains contributes directly to the
nutrition of hundreds of millions of citizens in other countries. The
nutritional circumstances of these consumers abroad can be improved, income can
be helped to grow even more rapidly (as new efficiencies are captured through
trade), and in many cases the environmental resources of these foreign
countries can be better protected through trade expansion. International
agricultural trade can be good for the environment in nations with dense
populations, scarce water, and fragile land endowments, since these nations
would damage their resource base if they tried to meet all of their growing
food needs without trade, through domestic production alone.
An important vision of the future thus
emerges; one which sees mutual gains from globalization, rather than only harsh
competition or painful adjustment. Trade expansion driven by broadly based
international economic development serves the interests of American agriculture
in harmony with the interests of foreign citizens and the global environment.
This is a vision worth pursuing through the wise conduct of U.S. government
policy.
This vision is founded in part on past
experience. Recent history provides abundant evidence that American agriculture
can benefit from policies designed to promote open trade and international
economic development. Yet the current policy climate brings distinct new
challenges, including large federal budget constraints, a weakening of the
traditional cold war security argument for investing in development cooperation
abroad, and a diminished public faith in all federal government programs. In
U.S. development policy, the era of big government is over. If gains for U.S.
agriculture are to continue to be captured, a new model for development
cooperation policy must be designed, one suited to today�s small government,
budget-constrained, post-Cold War era.
The new model we propose here relies more
on private sector actions and resources (both U.S. private companies, and U.S.
based Universities and PVOs), mobilized through partnership with
government agencies. The requirements for moving toward this partnership model
will be shown to include significant institutional changes within the U.S.
Agency for International Development (USAID), so as to make that agency a more
attractive partnering agent. The current tendency of Congress to try to
micro-manage U.S. trade and development policy must also change, and the
frequent subordination of development cooperation policy to short-term
diplomatic fluctuations must be minimized.
How can a political consensus be built to
embrace this new model of international trade and development cooperation
policy? We shall argue here that the U.S. agricultural sector has a strong
self-interest in development and trade policy revitalization, and should be
willing to take a leading role in arguing for the policy changes now required.
A strong endorsement from organized agriculture could be a key first step
toward making trade and development policy revitalization a political reality.
III. U.S. Assistance Policy in the Past:
A Success or a Failure?
During the Cold War era, U.S. development
assistance policy generated a mixed record, with some prominent successes alongside
numerous instances of failure. Humanitarian relief and human welfare assistance
policies were at times spectacularly successful. USAID support for child
inoculations and oral rehydration helped reduce infant mortality, as life
expectancy in poorer countries increased on average by more than 20 years (from
41 years to 62 years). In the 1980s alone, a major foreign assistance effort
led to a doubling of the proportion of people in developing countries with
access to clean water (from 35 percent to 70 percent). Adult literacy has risen
from less than half to about two-thirds. Food production and consumption in the
developing countries was able to increase 20 percent faster than population
growth (OECD 1996). The "green revolution" seed and farm production
technologies that made this increase possible would not have become available
without generous U.S. foreign assistance to international agricultural
research.
Of course much money has also been wasted
through foreign assistance. During the Cold War, billions of foreign aid
dollars were given to corrupt or incompetent regimes abroad for the purpose of
preserving base rights, buying diplomatic support, or securing votes in the UN
General Assembly in the high-stakes global competition with the Soviet Union.
During the Cold War, assistance seldom went for pure development purposes. It
is unsurprising that much of it failed to generate patterns of overall
development success.
Still, a remarkable number of nations
used this Cold War development assistance money wisely, sometimes with
spectacular results. The developing countries of East Asia, which were among
the first to side with the U.S. during the cold war (especially South Korea and
Taiwan), received generous early development assistance, and began growing
quickly as a result. During the years following 1945, Taiwan and South Korea
together received roughly $18.6 billion in U.S. economic and military aid
overall, plus sound technical and policy advice. The money and advice did not
go to waste, as South Korea and Taiwan embraced social policy reforms
(especially land reforms), made large investments in the health and education
of their own people, put sound macroeconomic policies in place, and committed
themselves to international trade. American agriculture was eventually the
beneficiary. As these nations industrialized rapidly and as incomes grew, they
increased their consumption of food and soon emerged as good customers for the
U.S. farm sector. Taiwan went from being a net exporter of cereals in
the 1950s to a $2.1 billion market for U.S. farm products today. South Korea is
now a $2.3 billion market for U.S. farm exports. Japan, which also received
generous assistance after 1945 (and which President Kennedy was still calling a
"developing country" as late as 1962), is now a $9.3 billion market
for U.S. agricultural exports.
Broad-based economic growth in the rest
of the developing world beyond East Asia would be a worthy development policy
goal for the U.S., since it would generate not only enormous citizen benefits
within those countries, but also economic benefits for the U.S. In recent
years, U.S. exporters of all products have become increasingly dependent on
income growth in the developing world. Between 1988-1994. total U.S. exports to
developing countries grew by 84 percent, more than twice the rate of growth of
exports to developed regions such as Europe.
The problem is that some developing
country regions are not yet generating the income growth that drives this sort
of trade expansion. The World Bank is currently forecasting only a .9 percent
annual growth rate in per capita GDP in sub-Saharan Africa between now and
2003, far below the 6.2 percent growth rate expected in East Asia (Alexandratos
1995). If Africa grows no more than this, the absolute numbers of hungry people
on that continent will continue to increase, and Africans will lack the income
needed to make their growing demands for food felt in the world�s commercial
market place.
Much has been learned over the past
several decades about what kinds of development efforts work best. USAID has
conducted frequent evaluations of its past programs, and has even been able to
measure its past success in the agricultural sector in quantitative terms. It
can demonstrate that economic rates of return to its investments in
agricultural technology development and diffusion, even in difficult settings
such as Africa, have averaged 30-40 percent over the years (USAID 1996). Still,
a number of difficult tactical lessons have been learned which implicitly set
limits on what can be done:
��������������� Sound policies within the
recipient country are especially important. USAID has concluded it should
invest only reluctantly, if at all, in countries where an adverse economic
policy environment prevails.
��������������� In agriculture, technology plays
a central role. The transformation of the farming sector requires technical
change, and investments in adaptive technological change pay large dividends.
��������������� Rural infrastructure and human
capital have underlying importance. Without an educated and empowered
population, and without roads from farm to market, rural communities cannot
respond to markets even if technology is available and prices are right.
With this growth in policy knowledge has
come renewed success. USAID today can point to an important new development
assistance success story in its support for the production of non-traditional
agricultural exports (NTAEs) from Latin America. USAID provided significant
support, especially in the 1980s, to Central and South American countries
seeking to diversify their farm export sectors beyond traditional crops such as
coffee, bananas, cotton, beef, and sugarcane, into "non-traditional"
crops such as melons, berries, citrus fruits, mangos, and flowers. This USAID support,
successfully undertaken in a context of larger political and policy changes
underway in the region (including democratization and structural adjustment),
helped generate an increase in NTAE exports profitable for all concerned. In
1970, Latin America and the Caribbean exported $200 million in NTAEs; by 1993,
the figure had jumped to over $1.65 billion.
This recent NTAE success clearly
demonstrates that USAID investments can pay off in the recipient country. Per
dollar of project expenditures in Central America and Ecuador, USAID money
generated internal rates of return of 15 percent and 22 percent, respectively.
The payoff was also strong from the vantage point of social justice, since NTAE
production has boosted incomes of the rural poor, including especially women.
In Central America, most NTAE production units are family farms from one to
five hectares in size. Production is highly labor-intensive, employing up to
eight times more person-days per hectare than traditional agriculture.
Guatemalan snowpeas provide farmers with an average of ten times the gross
income obtainable from corn, and an average of 13 times the gross income
obtainable from coffee. In Guatemala, the poorest 25 percent of the people have
captured 20 percent of the income gains from NTAE expansion, much more than the
3 percent gain they make, on average, from growth in the rest of the nation�s
economy.
What does the NTAE case mean for U.S.
agriculture? Most of the gains for NTAE producers in Latin America pose little
or no threat to farmers in the U.S. The NTAEs being exported either don�t
compete with significant numbers of U.S. farmers at all (mangos), or they go to
market during winter months, when U.S. producers cannot provide supplies
anyway. This is why the total volume of U.S. fruit and vegetable exports has
continued to increase in recent years (by about 40 percent, between 1990-1995),
despite the NTAE success in Central and South America.
For U.S. producers, increased product
availability from Latin America during the winter months can even be a plus,
since it tends to reinforce and sustain the taste of U.S. consumers for fresh
fruits and vegetables year-around. All the while, production of NTAEs in Latin
America is a significant boost to U.S. agricultural machinery and input supply
industries, which make larger sales as production in the hemisphere continues
to grow. NTAE imports from Latin America are also, of course, a substantial
gain for U.S. consumers, who are increasingly attracted to the health
advantages of year-round fresh fruit and vegetable consumption.
This NTAE example from Latin America is
only the most recent example of a development assistance success story. As with
the earlier East Asia case, it illustrates a larger truth. Economic success
abroad is good for agriculture in the U.S. Even when U.S. foreign assistance
efforts are directed toward increasing agricultural production in
poor countries, the larger results can still be complementary with the
interests of the farm sector in the U.S.
IV. Does U.S. Assistance to Foreign
Agricultural Production Hurt or Help U.S. Agriculture?
It seems paradoxical at first, but
assistance to farming in poor tropical countries is one of the best ways to
generate the broad-based income growth that those countries need to become
better customers for U.S. exports, including U.S. agricultural exports. The
World Bank confirms that most of the developing countries experiencing rapid
income growth in the 1980s previously experienced rapid agricultural growth
(World Bank 1996). Because so many people still live in the countryside in poor
countries, it is often impossible to launch a successful industrial revolution
without first investing in a broadly- based agricultural revolution.
U.S. farmers and farm exporters
appreciate the need for trade expansion, and they generally understand the need
to stimulate broad based income growth in poor countries, but they sometimes
worry about the dangers of trying to do that by providing aid to farmers
abroad, whom they tend to view as potential competitors. There are
circumstances in which this worry would be fully justified. If USAID were to
provide assistance to corn or soybean producers in Brazil or Argentina, the
impact on U.S. corn and soybean farmers would be adverse, rather than positive.
This is in part because corn and soybeans are temperate zone crops, but also it
is because of the unfortunate structure of farming in Brazil and Argentina,
where the income gains from improved production tend to be captured mostly by a
narrowly based land owning and agribusiness elite. In such countries where the
income gains from farming are not widely shared, the higher consumption and
import demands that should accompany agricultural success tend not to emerge.
But USAID does not provide assistance to
corn and soybean producers in countries like Brazil and Argentina. In the
countries where U.S. assistance programs have been active, gains in the
agricultural sector have produced enough broadly-based income growth to ensure
that the net effects on U.S. agricultural exporters will be positive rather
than negative. A number of studies have reached this conclusion over the past
dozen years, including Lee and Shane 1985; Kellogg, Kodl, and Garcia 1986;
Houck 1987; Anderson 1987; and de Janvry, Sadoulet, and White 1989. Such
studies have confirmed that helping poor tropical countries to launch an
agricultural revolution can make them better customers for U.S. exports,
including in the end U.S. farm exports.
A more recent confirmation of this
important finding is presented in a 1995 IFPRI study by Pinstrup-Andersen,
Lundberg, and Garrett. This study shows that about 20 percent of agricultural
exports from industrial countries now go to developing countries, and that U.S.
sales to these developing countries are expected in the years ahead to grow at
roughly 9 percent annually, or roughly twice the rate of growth of sales to
developed countries. Paradoxically, one of the drivers behind this import
growth in developing countries is growth in the agricultural output of those
countries. For all developing countries together, every extra dollar of
agricultural output actually adds to agricultural imports, because
agricultural growth helps push up personal income nation-wide, triggering more
broad-based demand for food. Each dollar of added agricultural output means 73
cents more in total imports, 17 cents more in agricultural imports, and 7 cents
more in cereal imports specifically. This paradoxical positive link is stronger
in East Asia than in some other regions such as Latin America or South Asia. As
noted above, agricultural growth in Latin America does not have the same
broadly-based income multiplier effects as in developing country regions where
land is more equitably distributed, and South Asia has in the past not been
very open to trade. But everywhere these links are nonetheless positive
(Pinstrup-Andersen, Lundberg, and Garrett 1995). The correlation also holds up
within regions. A recent study done by USAID�s Latin American and
Caribbean region concluded that those countries which showed the largest
increases in annual GDP were those in which the agricultural sector performance
was improving because of sub-sector diversification initiatives. These were the
same countries where trade with the U.S. (including exports of U.S. farm and
agribusiness products) grew most rapidly.
U.S. non-farm exporters also benefit, of
course, when agricultural development takes off in poor countries. Between
1990-95, due to more rapid growth in a number of agrarian-based countries,
total U.S. exports to those countries doubled to reach a level of $243 billion,
thus generating 1.9 million U.S. jobs across all sectors of the American
workforce (Bathrick 1996).
Development assistance to farmers in poor
countries is therefore not just compatible with the interests of those
countries and with larger American values. It is also directly compatible with
the long term interests of the U.S. economy, including the American farm sector
itself. Helping to support an agricultural revolution in poor countries is usually
the best first step toward helping to support a broadly-based industrial
revolution, and it is only from the broadly-based income gains that accompany
industrial development abroad that the American farm sector will be able to
enjoy continuously expanding sales opportunities in the decades ahead.
V. The New Challenge in Development
Cooperation
The historical record shows that U.S.
foreign assistance, even when given mostly for cold war purposes, managed often
to generate considerable development success, helping to pull people out of
poverty and increase food consumption, all to the benefit of the
export-dependent U.S. farm sector. With the end of the Cold War, the U.S. faces
an opportunity to improve on this past record, by shifting a larger share of
our assistance budget away from political or military support activities, and
toward the economic development activities that can be more broadly beneficial
to foreign income growth and hence to U.S. exporters of farm and non-farm
products.
Unfortunately, the end of the Cold War
has not brought any increase in U.S. development assistance activities. When
the Cold War enemy in Moscow collapsed, the political inclination at home to
support any kind of foreign assistance effort also declined. In mid 1993, a
National Security Council study of foreign aid policy options stated flatly
that "with the disappearance of communism in the Soviet Union and Eastern
Europe, the bedrock support for foreign assistance has eroded significantly.
There is no clear vision guiding the shape of our foreign assistance agenda for
a world without the USSR." The several comprehensive visions that have
since been suggested to support assistance (including "conflict
prevention," "big emerging markets," and "global
stewardship") have not yet caught hold. Consequently, U.S. assistance
efforts have gone into a steep fall. Last year alone, according to the OECD,
total U.S. official development assistance fell 27 percent, to just $7.3
billion.
Under recent congressional projections,
the U.S. international affairs budget (the so-called 150 account, of which
two-thirds is foreign assistance) may be further cut by an additional one-third
in real terms between now and 2002. President Clinton has now proposed a
reversal of this downward trend (he is seeking a $1.3 billion increase in the
150 account for FY 1998, above the $18.2 billion that Congress voted for FY
1997), yet Congress will have to be persuaded, and even with such an increase
the 150 account would be about 25 percent less in real terms than the average
during the decade of the 1980s.
These cuts have transformed the U.S. from
a leader into a laggard among industrial countries engaged in development
cooperation work abroad. U.S. development assistance is now only about half the
amount provided by Japan, and less in absolute terms than the amount provided
by either France or Germany. Relative to GNP, the U.S. development assistance
budget is now the smallest in the industrial world. The U.S. ranks 21st among
industrialized (OECD) countries - dead last - in providing development
assistance abroad. Since 1970 the U.S. government has been pledged to provide
0.7 percent of GNP as official development assistance (a pledge reaffirmed as
recently as 1992 at the UNCED conference in Rio), but the actual U.S.
contribution has recently been just 0.1 percent, less than one third the ratio
of most other industrial countries. Other industrial countries are impatient
with U.S. excuses for this lagging performance. In Europe, where budget
pressures are just as bad as in the U.S. and where domestic unemployment levels
are currently much higher, governments have nonetheless been more willing to
maintain their international development cooperation investments.
This lagging U.S. assistance effort is
partly an outgrowth of the recent federal budget crisis. By 1993 the U.S.
government�s debt-to-GDP ratio had reached 56.9 percent, more than twice the
level of two decades earlier, and serious efforts to attack the budget deficits
generating this debt had to be undertaken. For political reasons these efforts
could not focus on cutting entitlement spending (Democrats would object), or on
restoring lost tax revenues (Republicans would object), so pressures grew to
cut spending elsewhere, and in a post-Cold War environment foreign aid
naturally became an inviting target. All the more so because the international
affairs budget was placed within the "non-defense discretionary
funding" category (the 17 percent of the U.S. federal budget which, under
a 1996 deficit reduction agreement, had to absorb nearly one half of all
spending reductions). The prejudicial quality of these budgeting procedures
became apparent in 1996 when the same U.S. Congress that was cutting
development assistance by $2.6 billion in a single year actually voted to increase
defense spending. The House voted to increase the Administration�s request
for defense by $11 billion for FY 1997.
Public misinformation is another reason
for the recent excessive cuts in foreign assistance spending. A University of Maryland
poll shows that the American people erroneously believe that 15 percent of the
federal budget goes to foreign aid, when the actual figure is only one percent.
A Washington Post poll revealed that the American people thought more
was spent on foreign aid than on Medicare, when in fact the foreign aid budget
is less than one twentieth the Medicare budget, and shrinking rather than
growing. If the American people could appreciate how modest and affordable our
foreign development cooperation efforts have actually been in budget terms,
they would be less likely to support the current congressional inclination to
shrink those efforts still farther.
Popular mistrust of government has become
another powerful cause of diminished political support for foreign assistance.
The American people are not becoming any less concerned about poverty abroad,
or any less generous in their desire to do something about it, but it seems
they are less ready to believe that spending money through their federal
government is an effective way to attack poverty. Large numbers of Americans
have come to be convinced that public sector bureaucracies are not as good as
private sector institutions (including business firms, and also non-profit
PVOs) in taking on practical tasks. A survey taken in 1972 showed that 53
percent of Americans still trusted the government to do what is right
"most of the time," but by 1986 only 39 percent of Americans felt
that way, and by 1992 only 27 percent felt that way (Shively 1995, p. 124).
One of the most puzzling and frustrating
features of the recent collapse in U.S. foreign development cooperation
spending has been a sharp cut in funding provided specifically for agriculture.
Between 1989 and 1994, while the nominal value of total U.S. economic assistance
through USAID remained roughly constant (at about $6 billion), the value of
assistance to agriculture declined in nominal terms by 48 percent, from $806
million down to just $418 million (USAID 1996). USAID�s agricultural work was
being cut early in the 1990s partly because the agency was now targeting
several other objectives - including the slowing of population growth, women�s
health, environment, democratization, and micro-enterprise development. These
are worthy objectives, but it must be remembered that they cannot be pursued in
rural areas without a strong program in agriculture. Rural women�s health
and welfare in Africa depends heavily on productive and profitable agriculture,
since women make up the majority of Africa�s farmers. Microenterprise
development in rural areas usually means supplying inputs to farming or
providing storage, transport, and processing for products from the farm. Rural
environmental protection will be impossible if farming is not prudently
intensified. So any future U.S. development cooperation program that
downplays agriculture will be a program certain to exclude the well-being of
large numbers of rural citizens in poor countries.
One unfortunate reason for diminished
U.S. support for development cooperation in agriculture has been the loud voice
of one school of environmental activism (Easterbrook 1997). A vocal minority of
activists within the environmental community opposes further investment in
rapid economic growth abroad (income growth based on industrial development is
seen as "non-sustainable") and within the farm sector some of these
environmental groups have embraced an extreme vision of low-input subsistence
farming, one which rules out efforts to boost farm income through
yield-enhancing purchased inputs, even though such inputs were a key to the
success of the green revolution in India thirty years ago. These activists also
oppose any switch from subsistence to export crops, even though export crops
(such as those which are key to the NTAE success in Latin America in the 1990s)
often do less damage to fragile lands and give small farmers more income.
Environmental activists are correct to be
concerned about excessive farm chemical use, but this is more of a problem in
rich industrial countries than in poor countries. Excessive input use is a
problem in industrial countries where farm production tends to be subsidized,
more than in the developing world where farmers still tend to be heavily taxed
by government policies. In developing country regions such as Africa,
environmental damage from farming tends to grow from a pattern of purchased
input use which is inadequate rather than excessive. Fertilizer use per acre in
Africa is only one quarter the level of India, and only one-thirty-sixth the
level of Japan. It is only by increasing yields per acre - in part through
purchased inputs - that Africa�s farmers will be able to avoid further
deforestation and further plowing of fragile lands in the years just ahead.
India�s experience (and the experience of
much of the rest of Asia) during the green revolution of the 1960s and 1970s
can be used to illustrate this point. If India had relied on traditional
low-yielding seed varieties and farming techniques to try to increase its total
production to feed its growing population in the 1960s and 1970s, it would have
had no choice but to clear more land, cut more trees, destroy more wildlife
habitat, ruin upper watersheds by planting crops on sloping lands, or plow up
more dry lands with fragile soils. In 1964, India produced 12 million tons of
wheat on 14 million hectares of land. By 1993, thanks to the green revolution,
it was producing 57 million tons of wheat on 24 million hectares of land,
allowing its much larger population to be somewhat better fed. To produce this
much wheat using at the 1964 yield level (using pre-green revolution seed
varieties and technologies), India would have had to plant roughly 60 million
hectares. In other words, the green revolution allowed India to meet evolving
food needs without plowing an additional 36 million hectares of cropland
for wheat. "Thanks to plant breeding," concluded M. S. Swaminathan,
at India�s Centre for Research on Sustainable Agriculture and Rural
Development, "a tremendous onslaught on fragile lands and forest margins
has been avoided." (Swaminathan 1994).
Foreign development cooperation programs
have helped protect the rural environment in other ways as well. International
(including USAID) support for integrated pest management (IPM) practices has
helped a number of developing countries reduce dependence on potentially
dangerous pesticides. Technical assistance in "precision farming"
helps to reduce excessive applications of chemical fertilizers. The trade policy
reforms promoted by the U.S. government have also helped protect the
environment in some developing countries from unsound agricultural practices.
By encouraging nations such as Korea and Taiwan to open foodgrain markets
(especially rice) to imports, U.S. trade negotiators have helped ease the
adverse environmental impact of chemical-intensive rice production in these
countries. Compared to the U.S., Korea uses four times as much fertilizer per
acre of cropland and Taiwan uses five times as much.
Some of the reasons that seemed
persuasive in the past for cutting international cooperation programs in
agriculture are now quite suspect. One of these is a supposition that arose
when international commodity prices collapsed in the mid 1980s, the supposition
that "we have solved the world food crisis." This collapse of
international commodity prices in the mid 1980s was more the result of a world
recession than it was an indication that food problems were being solved. In
fact, the world recession and debt crisis of the mid 1980s led to a significant
increase in poverty and unemployment (and hence hunger) in many
developing countries, especially in Latin America and Africa. The deeply
depressed international commodity prices of the mid 1980s are for the moment no
longer with us in any case, and FAO projects that with or without low
international prices the total number of chronically undernourished people in
Africa will increase over the next two decades, from 175 million to 296
million by 2010.
Another suspect explanation for cutting
international cooperation programs in agriculture is the frequently heard
argument (it is an especially strong refrain among some inside the World Bank)
that "agricultural projects tend to fail." Those that make this
charge are looking at old numbers, and often at the wrong numbers. The
proportion of World Bank projects in agriculture that failed in the past was
indeed higher than in other sectors, but failure rates per dollar invested
were respectably low for agricultural projects, at least everywhere except
Africa. The economic rate of return on all agricultural project lending
evaluated by the World Bank between 1967 and 1987 was 17.8 percent, almost
identical to the Bank-wide average of 17.9 percent (Lipton and Paarlberg 1990).
Many of the agricultural lending projects that failed in Africa and Latin
America in the 1970s and 1980s were complex, large-area "integrated rural
development" projects of the kind that are no longer being undertaken. And
today the World Bank is justifiably proud of the performance of its
agricultural projects. In fiscal 1996, 78 percent of completed agricultural
projects at the Bank were rated satisfactory, which is 10 percentage points
above the Bank average for projects in all sectors (World Bank 1996). Public
policy perceptions clearly have not yet caught up with all of these realities.
U.S. development cooperation policies should be building on past success, and
should be helping to create the broad-based income growth in poor countries
that will be essential for U.S. agricultural success in future years, but
instead those policies have been threatened with dismantlement.
VI. The New Challenge in Trade
Open trade policies will also be critical
if prosperity abroad is to produce gains for U.S. agriculture at home. NAFTA in
1993 and the Uruguay Round in 1994 produced strong gains in the opening up of
foreign markets to larger U.S. farm exports (for a summary of these gains, see
Sek and Hanrahan 1996). But much more remains to be done in implementing these
agreements, and in negotiating further market opening agreements elsewhere in
the Western Hemisphere, across the Pacific, and with Europe. A NAFTA
enlargement to include Chile, and a Free Trade Area of the Americas (FTAA) are
waiting to be negotiated; the new dispute settlement powers of the WTO are now
waiting to be used by the U.S. to maximum advantage; and in the WTO a new round
of negotiations on agriculture, due to start in 1999, is already in
preparation. The issues that might be addressed in this new negotiating round
could include increased market access, further reductions in market-distorting
domestic supports for agriculture, new disciplines on export subsidies, and
better defined, scientifically justified sanitary and phytosanitary (SPS)
import barriers. One issue that this next round might address, from the vantage
point of U.S. agriculture, will be the issue of state trading entities (STE),
such as the Canadian Wheat Board. The characteristics of these STEs give them
considerable potential to distort markets through monopsony/monopoly powers,
hidden subsidies, and hence export price distortions. The Uruguay Round
agreement did not do enough to
discipline STEs. In the next round an
opportunity will exist to bring the transactions of STEs under greater discipline,
or at least make them more transparent.
In the face of this full and promising
agenda of new trade policy opportunities, U.S. leadership on trade has
unfortunately faltered. In the aftermath of the Mexican peso crisis of 1994-95,
populist sentiments against additional free trade measures temporarily became
stronger within both parties. Efforts to restore the President�s "fast
track" negotiating authority (a necessary congressional action, if U.S.
negotiators are to be credible in talks abroad) have so far been unavailing.
Democrats in Congress won�t renew fast track authority unless it is broad
enough to make possible the negotiation of parallel guarantees on labor or the
environment, while Republicans in Congress believe that further progress toward
trade liberalization should not be held hostage to such guarantees.
To keep U.S. trade policy on hold because
of memories of the 1994 Mexican peso crisis is illogical. That crisis (which is
now largely repaired in any case) was not caused by NAFTA. It was the result of
mismanagement of domestic credit by the central bank of Mexico. If NAFTA had
not been in place in 1994, Mexico might have responded to this crisis in an
even more damaging fashion, by raising import tariffs (just as it did in the
earlier 1982 crisis). It is also illogical to allow U.S. trade negotiators to
remain paralyzed by partisan differences over a broad versus narrow
reauthorization of fast track authority. Trade policy should be fertile ground
for bipartisan cooperation, as it was when a Democratic Congress gave broad
fast track authority to a Republican President in 1988, and when Republicans in
Congress helped a pro-trade Democratic President secure implementing
legislation for NAFTA and the Uruguay Round Agreements in 1993 and 1994.
In the area of trade policy, it is not
only barriers abroad that need to be lowered, of course. Poor countries abroad
will not be able to grow and become better customers for U.S. exports
(including farm exports) if they are denied reciprocal access to U.S. markets.
By some estimates, industrial country tariffs and non-tariff trade barriers now
cost developing countries $40 billion a year, which is equal to two-thirds of
the total dollar value of all development aid from the industrial countries. In
1994, ten thousand African workers lost their jobs when U.S. trade officials
placed restrictions on imports of shirts and pillowcases from Kenya. If the
U.S. had behaved this way toward the successful infant textile manufacturers
and exporters of East Asia thirty or forty years ago, that region of the world
would not be the development success story it is today, or the good customer
that it is today for U.S. agricultural exports. Enlightened trade and
development cooperation policies thus must apply to all if they are to work
well together.
VII. Responding to the Development
Challenge: Improving Delivery Systems
Popular support for U.S. development
cooperation policy will be hard to secure without a significant redesign of the
institutional "delivery system" currently being used to promote
development abroad. The system currently in use is unsatisfactory, for a number
of reasons:
��������������� Too Much Central Regulation.
USAID headquarters hampers its own field staff with too many top-down
regulations. In USAID�s recent reduction in force, it is unfortunate that
senior staff in Washington were cut less than junior staff in the field. Senior
staff retained in Washington must make work for themselves, so they
over-regulate the activities of a dwindling number of junior colleagues in the
field.
��������������� Too Much Congressional
Micro-management. Congress hamstrings and overburdens USAID by establishing
too many competing objectives. A 1989 report from the House Foreign Affairs
Committee actually identified 33 different and independent statutory
goals and objectives for USAID and (believe it or not) 75 different
"priority" areas. Congressional earmarking is also a burdensome
practice. As of FY 1993, approximately 57 percent of Development Assistance
(DA) from USAID and 84 percent of the Economic Support Fund (ESF) and 96
percent of Foreign Military Financing (FMF) was earmarked. Sometimes it is the
non-responsiveness of the USAID bureaucracy that forces Congress and outside
groups to resort to the earmarking approach, but it is an unfortunate approach
all the same, since it gets in the way of flexible decision making. Earmarks
take discretionary authority away from officials on the scene and generate
irrationalities in the expenditure of funds. Congress decided many years ago
that it should not try to micro-manage U.S. monetary policy (when it created
the semi-autonomous Federal Reserve Board), and it later reached the same
conclusion in the area of U.S. trade policy (when it created the
semi-autonomous Office of the U.S. Trade Representative). Regrettably it has
not yet overcome the temptation to mico-manage U.S. development cooperation
policy abroad.
��������������� Difficulties Cooperating With
the Private Sector. USAID�s excessive headquarters regulation,
inflexibility, and congressional micro-management is especially damaging when
it hampers efforts to cooperate with private U.S. companies, universities, and
PVOs. In the field, PVOs lose patience and give up when they discover that the
local USAID representative has no discretion to provide funding for good new
proposals, or can only provide funding after a long delay, or can only provide
funding with onerous strings attached, such as impossible reporting or
procurement requirements. Contracting partners in the U.S. pull out their hair
when USAID forces them into a wasteful and repetitive competition with each
other, responding to thick, turgid, innovation-killing and overly-specified
RFPs. Even if a contractor wins this competition, it will then face such delay
and uncertainty in getting the money that staffing and budgeting efforts will
be a shambles. Private U.S. business firms that must move fast to seize
profitable investment opportunities can�t accommodate USAID�s sluggish response
time, and are often exasperated to learn just how constrained the U.S.
government has become (in contrast to governments in Europe, or Japan) in
working cooperatively with U.S. business corporations.
��������������� Too Many Short Term Diplomatic
and Security Constraints. Yet another source of institutional trouble with
the U.S. development cooperation delivery system is the persistent intrusion of
short-term diplomatic and security concerns. Even in today�s post-Cold War
environment, State Department and Defense Department concerns have an
unfortunate way of swamping the Administration by assistance professionals of
long-term development cooperation efforts. A large part of the USAID budget is
not allocated with economic growth purposes in mind, but rather in pursuit of
military security or short term diplomatic cooperation. These are worthy
purposes on their own terms, and sometimes they can provide a substantial
collateral boost in the area of broad economic development (for example in
Korea and Taiwan, as noted above), but they can also get in the way of a sound
development strategy. Development cooperation has to work over the long term,
and the long view can be disrupted if assistance funds are extended or
withdrawn in response to short term diplomatic or security priorities.
Development opportunities can be lost if funds that could be going to nations
or regions with rapid income growth potential are hijacked instead to help
finance international security efforts or diplomatic understandings. The
Vietnam War badly distorted the global distribution of U.S. assistance funds in
this fashion in the 1960s and 1970s, and since the late 1970s an open ended
priority given to financing peace agreements in the Middle East (at a cost of
roughly $5 billion a year to support the twenty year old Camp David agreements)
has left fewer funds available for priority development cooperation work
elsewhere.
��������������� Too Little Coordination With
Other Agencies. A fourth source of institutional trouble has been poor
coordination between USAID and other U.S. government agencies such as Commerce,
Agriculture, and most of all the Treasury Department, which takes the lead in
managing U.S. contributions toward international financial institutions such as
the World Bank.
Reacting to this summary view of existing
flaws, at least three large objectives should be pursued in any effort to
redesign U.S. foreign development cooperation institutions: an increased
capacity to build wide-ranging development cooperation partnerships, a
reduction in congressional micro-management, and a reduction in subordination
to short term diplomatic concerns.
Closer Partnerships
All core U.S. development cooperation
agencies (starting with USAID) need to increase their capacity to form closer
partnerships and alliances with other U.S. government agencies, with
multilateral organizations, with other donor governments, with recipient
governments, with private U.S. firms, and with U.S. PVOs (plus the larger
networks within which those PVOs operate). We shall describe, below, what some
of these improved partnerships might look like, especially with business firms
and PVOs. But to form these partnerships, USAID must make itself a more
inviting institutional ally. It needs to develop a stronger capacity throughout
for flexible, autonomous action, and it needs to free up its field officers
from excessive headquarters regulation. It needs to stop over-specifying
program design, and be quicker and more flexible with its commitment and
delivery of financial resources. It needs to be less squeamish about entrusting
a part of the development cooperation task to profit-making U.S. companies.
USAID tells recipient governments to trust the private sector, but too often it
distances itself from - or seeks to over-regulate - its potential partners
within the U.S. private sector. And it needs also to learn how to network more
effectively, both at headquarters and in-country, with U.S. PVOs and the larger
PVO community. USAID officials today spend too much time advancing and
protecting their careers through network-building activities within the
corridors of the agency itself, and not enough time building alliances and
partnerships with PVOs, with investors in the private sector, and with
officials in allied agencies or organizations.
Reduced Micromanagement from Congress
A second large institutional reform
objective, corollary to the first, must be to reduce the degree of USAID
micro-management by Congress. The encrusted language of the original Foreign
Assistance Act needs to be revised to include more explicit support for trade,
environment, and equity. Statutory program objectives should be described in
less burdensome number and detail. Appropriations earmarks should be minimized,
and reporting requirements should be made less onerous. Also, Congressional
oversight of USAID should be conducted more often at a distance, and more by
the substantive authorizing committees of Congress (Foreign Affairs and Foreign
Relations), and less by the appropriations committees. The annual
appropriations process tends to reflect short-term perspectives of
non-specialist members who may have only district or partisan concerns (or at
best only budget number concerns) in mind. Ideally, U.S. development
cooperation policies should be funded from a longer term perspective, either
through a long term institutional grant, or through self-replenishing
instruments such as revolving funds.
Reduced Dictation from the Foreign
Policy Community
A significant portion of U.S. assistance
abroad during the Cold War went through the Economic Support Fund (ESF). The
ESF provided U.S. diplomats with the "walking around money" they
needed to round up allies in the battle to contain communism. With the end of
the cold war, these funds have been cut steeply, and an opportunity has arisen
to free the rest of the U.S. development cooperation budget from the often
damaging effects of short term fluctuations in U.S. diplomatic relations
abroad. Short-term diplomatic conflicts with foreign governments over human
rights violations, drug trafficking, or nuclear weapons programs should not
have to get in the way of longer term development cooperation efforts. These
efforts can be designed to promote private markets and boost the health,
welfare, and income of poor citizens, not the governments of those citizens.
When long term development cooperation efforts are interrupted as a consequence
of short term diplomatic difficulties, those diplomatic difficulties are
frequently worsened in any case.
ESF activities might appropriately remain
under the direction of the U.S. diplomatic community, but other development
cooperation activities, if they are to be successful on their own terms (and if
they are to attract a sufficient number of partners from the private sector,
from PVO networks, and from the multilateral assistance community), deserve a
degree of insulation from the daily business of diplomacy. The U.S.
agricultural community should be especially sympathetic to this requirement,
since it has been damaged in the past by excessive foreign policy dictation.
The 1980-81 grain embargo, imposed on U.S. agriculture by the foreign policy
community, did little to punish the Soviet Union (for its invasion Afghanistan)
yet the embargo created for U.S. grain exporters a long-term credibility
problem in the minds of potentially valuable foreign customers who did not wish
to make themselves vulnerable, in the event of future diplomatic difficulties,
to a possible renewal of foreign policy driven embargo tactics.
Whenever it is suggested that U.S.
development cooperation programs should be given greater insulation from U.S.
diplomatic operations, some friends of those programs worry that the broader
political coalition that has helped generate congressional support for these
programs could become split or weakened. Perhaps Congress, if not given an
integrated budget for all international affairs activities, might begin
selectively to fund just aid for the Middle East, while imposing even deeper
cuts on real development cooperation elsewhere. This is a significant concern,
yet there are just as many tactical arguments on the other side.
A complete subordination of development
cooperation policy to diplomatic calculations is currently the preference of
some leaders in Congress. We believe this approach would bring serious costs.
Development cooperation activities need greater independence from the State
Department, not greater subordination.
VIII. Institutional Change: Long Term and
Short Term Goals
The long-term objective should be to
redesign USAID as a more independent institution, less burdened by
congressional micro-management, less hampered by short term diplomatic
calculations, and better able to partner with other public and private sector
institutions. A number of specific reorganization proposals are now circulating
that would seem to meet these requirements. For example, the Overseas
Development Council has recently proposed housing bilateral U.S. development
assistance in an International Development Foundation, an operational
grant-making entity that would focus on a limited set of achievable development
challenges jointly agreed on by the Executive Branch and Congress. To make this
foundation attractive to potential partners, and to give those partners a healthy
measure of "ownership" in program activities, the grant-making
process would be substantially demand driven.
Some prominent agriculturalist reform
advocates are also on record supporting elements of this approach. Professor
Vernon Ruttan of the University of Minnesota has proposed moving the bulk of
USAID�s bilateral economic development and humanitarian assistance activities
into two new semi-autonomous entities, one designed to foster
sub-contracting partnerships with universities, research institutes, and
relevant departments of other U.S. government agencies (e.g. Agriculture,
Commerce, EPA), with funding provided not through annual appropriations but
through a long-term institutional grant, and the other designed to build
partnerships with PVOs and private firms, funding programs on a competitive bid
basis. Ruttan points to the success of a number of public foundations already
in existence, including the Asia Foundation, the Inter-American Development
Foundation, and the African Development Foundation, as precedents that lend
credibility to this approach (Ruttan 1996).
Such proposals envisioning a
semi-autonomous entity for delivering development cooperation policy have
periodically enjoyed a significant degree of support in Congress. In 1989, a bipartisan
proposal not so different from the Ruttan proposal actually came close to being
enacted into law. The International Economic Cooperation Act (H.R. 655) was
passed the U.S. House of Representatives by a 314-101 margin. The House bill
did not go as far as might be preferred in reducing the practice of country and
program earmarking, or in transferring funds from ESF to genuine development
assistance, but it did place heavy stress on partnerships with PVOs,
universities, and the private sector. This measure later failed to become law
when a parallel authorization bill never reached the Senate floor for a vote.
The long-term goal, over the next several
years, should be to rebuild a consensus for this nearly successful move toward
increased institutional flexibility and independence at USAID. In the political
climate of 1997, however, it seems unlikely that such a move could gain support
from the key congressional committee chairs and executive branch officials
needed to ensure success. In the political climate of 1997, it might be unwise
to embark upon a radical dismantling of the existing institutional structure at
USAID, since there are those in today�s Congress that seem to prefer a
development agency that is even weaker and less independent than the one we
currently have.
As a short term strategy, therefore, we
prefer to press changes onto USAID administratively, or through a reprogramming
of funds in the direction of the various partnering activities we are
describing here, rather than legislatively through a complete rewrite of the
Foreign Assistance Act. We believe there are abundant short-term opportunities
to engage administratively in this sort of redirection and reprogramming.
IX. Opportunities to Move Toward
Partnership
We have stressed the importance of
creating a development cooperation delivery system that enlarges the space
available to form alliances or partnerships with other public sector agencies
at home and abroad, and between the public and the private sector. Why are such
partnerships attractive, and, in practice, what might these partnerships look
like? Different partners might be attractive for different reasons and
purposes.
Multilateral Agencies
The reasons to partner with multilateral
agencies are mostly financial. Small U.S. initiatives taken through
multilateral institutions, such as the Consultative Group on International
Agricultural Research (CGIAR) or the International Development Association
(IDA) inside the World Bank, can leverage parallel contributions that might not
otherwise be made by other wealthy country governments, in Japan and Europe.
This is an opportunity currently being underutilized. In 1996, only about 10
percent of U.S. aid resources went through multilateral agencies. The Overseas
Development Council and others strongly support multilateralization. Other
donors have been more aggressive than the U.S. in capturing multilateral funds
to support their own specific interests (specifically to support employment of
their own nationals as consultants), but this is a problem that might be more
easily addressed if the U.S. role working with multilateral agencies were
enlarged.
The imperative to leverage
internationally is strong. Worldwide, the U.S. now provides only about
one-sixth of the total volume of official development assistance, and can have
much greater influence over the remaining five-sixths if it works through
multilateral institutions. Within the World Bank, U.S. leverage is now being
lost due to reduced U.S. contributions to the International Development Agency
(IDA), the long- term low interest loan window at the Bank. For FY 1997,
President Clinton requested $934 million for the IDA, but Congress approved
only $700 million. U.S. failures to honor earlier commitments to the IDA
actually resulted in the exclusion of some U.S. companies from participation in
IDA projects, confirming that there can be a direct cost to U.S. interests from
non-cooperation in multilateral settings.
The World Bank is also an attractive
partner on financial grounds because of the vast lending resources it can
mobilize at no cost to U.S. taxpayers, when it borrows funds from private
international capital markets. It is these financial strengths, in part, which
make multilateral financial institutions the best venue in which to pursue the
most expensive "bricks and mortar" aspects of development cooperation
policy abroad. Also the "policy dialogue" dimension. Borrowing
countries that need to reform their policies are more likely to listen if the
reform steps requested are conditions for large World Bank loans, rather than
conditions for the much smaller bilateral transfers that USAID can afford. For
such reasons, close partnership relations with multilateral agencies and
lending institutions are a necessary foundation for U.S. development
cooperation success abroad.
Building these partnerships is currently
difficult in part because it is the Department of the Treasury, not USAID, that
takes the lead in managing U.S. relations with multilateral development banks.
Some (such as the Overseas Development Council) have advocated giving this
management function to USAID. This is desirable, but politically unlikely. A
more probable remedy would be to redesign interagency (and inter-branch)
procedures. One suggestion is to form a "MDB Agriculture Task Force,"
composed of representatives from USDA, Commerce, USTR, USAID, and staff from
relevant House and Senate committees, to meet every two months so as to remain
abreast of Treasury/MDB policy initiatives (Bathrick 1996). In partnering with
MDBs, USAID brings an important resource to the table: a continuous in-country
staff presence at many locations in the developing world. Many MDB activities
are currently undertaken with little local knowledge on a thin foundation of
information gained only from brief on-site consultations. While USAID is
leveraging MDB financial resources, MDBs can thus be leveraging USAID field
staff expertise. Particularly if the USAID field staff in question are also
actively partnering with U.S. private companies, universities, and PVOs, all
will gain as a result.
Some non-MDB multilateral agencies are
also useful partners, even though they may not have significant financial
resources. The Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) of the UN, although at
times maligned for its bureaucratic procedures and frequent lack of
accountability, can help supplement U.S. development cooperation efforts to
good effect in a number of specialized areas. For example, it was through the
plant protection division of FAO that the U.S. government (with leadership from
EPA as well as USDA) helped broker an important agreement on safe use of
pesticides (the Prior Informed Consent provision of FAO�s Code of Conduct on
safe pesticide use), a rare instance in which common ground was established between
private international agrochemical industries and the activist international
environmental movement. FAO has also been instrumental in helping to promote
environmentally friendly integrated pest management (IPM) techniques,
especially in East and Southeast Asia, where insecticide use poses a serious
environmental and human health threat.
Other U.S. Government Agencies,
including State Governments
The reasons for USAID to partner with
other agencies of the U.S. government and also with state government are
self-evident. Many U.S. cabinet departments (including Agriculture) already
have a significant embassy-based presence abroad and substantial program
activities in numerous areas linked to development cooperation. The USAID of
the future should look beyond its own corridors and imagine partnering or
alliance opportunities with these other U.S. government agencies. The job of
international development cooperation is a big job, and should be done abroad
by a wide mix of U.S. government agencies including Commerce, Agriculture,
Treasury, USTR, EX-IM, OPIC, Peace Corps, EPA, NIH, Interior, and HHS. State
governments also invest heavily in promoting technical exchange and trade, and
should be included in the larger set of partnerships used to promote development
cooperation abroad.
One recent example of what other
government agencies can do in the development cooperation area is a new food
aid monetization activity in Cote d�Ivoire, in which USAID plays only a minor
role alongside USDA�s Food for Progress program, and a PVO, Winrock
International. Winrock sells USDA donated dark northern spring wheat in Cote
d�Ivoire, and uses the proceeds for both market development and economic
development, including support of the bread baking industry, training of bakers,
and also the education of women in agriculture and environmental sciences.
Through this partnership between USDA, and a U.S.-based PVO, multiple
objectives can be more effectively pursued. USAID should encourage such
activities by other agencies, as a means to escape the constraints presented by
its own limited budget resources.
Reasons to Partner with Foreign
Governments
U.S. development cooperation work abroad
will be most successful if it is done with foreign governments that feel
themselves to be "invested" in the process. The OECD has stated the
goal in plain language: "Acceptance of the partnership model... is one of
the most positive changes we are proposing in the framework for development
cooperation. In a partnership, development cooperation does not try to do
things for developing countries and their people, but with them. It must be
seen as a collaborative effort to help them increase their capacities to do
things for themselves. Paternalistic approaches have no place in this
framework." (OECD 1996, p. 14). This means that these foreign governments
need to be brought into the formulation of policy at an early enough stage to
feel a sense of ownership, and it means that USAID overseas personnel need to
be freely empowered to develop this sort of relationship with foreign
government counterparts. USAID personnel are already formally
"accredited" to other governments, giving them vital access to key
ministries, but too often they are hampered from seizing opportunities because
of top heavy intrusions from Washington, and because of stifling procedural
requirements, even when only small amounts of money are involved.
Reasons to Partner with PVOs and
Universities
Reasons to partner more extensively and
more effectively with U.S. PVOs and universities are abundant. As USAID sees
its own resources diminishing, it should seek opportunities to make more
effective use of PVO networks around the world. PVO personnel are often highly
motivated and well informed about the needs and circumstances of grass roots communities
in developing countries. They are often better trusted than official government
personnel in rural areas, and better able to work across the political dividing
lines within countries that can paralyze public sector development or relief
efforts.
Partnering with PVOs and universities can
best be accomplished on a case by case basis in-country, by USAID officials
given enough authority to respond to good project and program ideas generated
within local PVO networks. Moving USAID toward the model of a grant-making
foundation, the long run goal stated above, could increase local partnering
opportunities dramatically. In making funding decisions the U.S. representative
would respond to locally generated proposals, assess the quality of the program
(or innovation), its potential spread and sustainability, the special needs of
intended beneficiaries (women, children, vulnerable groups), benign
environmental effects, the commitment and caliber of the leadership of the PVO
both in the U.S. and in the cooperating country, and other criteria. A
"portfolio" of programs could be built with resulting impacts that
Americans as a whole could be proud of.
Grants would be made on a competitive
basis involving experienced and responsible country nationals. Necessary host
government approvals would be sought, but the funding process should be as
independent of government management as possible once agreement is reached on
the merits of an initiative. Grants might be for 5-10 years, with periodic
reviews during this time, reviews that could terminate the grant if funds are
not being used as agreed or the innovation is not demonstrating sufficient
payoff.
Such an approach to development
cooperation would be facilitated by a continuing U.S. official presence in
cooperating countries, but not the kind of high unit-cost presence exemplified
in today�s USAID missions. A selected cadre of development professionals who
have language, cultural, and other skills relevant to working with counterparts
in the particular country could evaluate proposals and then facilitate
partnership activities at relatively low cost to U.S. taxpayers. Not all
development efforts should be at the grass roots, of course. There are many
investments waiting to be made in infrastructure and institutional capacity
that only the public sector can finance. But if partnering opportunities with
grass roots PVOs and private sector firms are missed, public sector investments
alone will fall short.
Reasons to Partner with Private
Investors
Reasons to partner with private investors
are compelling. Private investments are an all-important source of development
support throughout Asia, Africa, and Latin America. While official governmental
aid (from all countries) has stagnated recently at $55 billion to $65 billion
annually, private investment in the developing world reached $167 billion last
year, up from $44 billion in 1990. Public resources have declined from
providing (as late as the 1980s) three-quarters of external financing to
development, to less than one quarter today. Any U.S. development cooperation
effort that fails to work with and help shape these increasingly important
private investment flows will steadily lose relevance.
As one example of an effective use of
private sector resources, consider the U.S./Newly Independent States (NIS)
Agribusiness Partnership, a joint ventures program begun in 1992, through which
some 22 agribusiness partnerships have now been initiated with support from two
USAID guarantees. The ratio of government to private financing is roughly 1 to
3.5, indicating a substantial leveraging of private resources. In twelve of
these joint ventures so far, satisfactory to excellent results have been
achieved in the development of long term business relationships designed to
increase food availability and quality in the states of the former Soviet Union
(five have experienced implementation problems, and the rest are too new to be
evaluated). The focus of these partnerships is on technical assistance and
transfer of western management skills through training on-the-job and
short-term, in areas such as meat processing and marketing, potato production,
and corn processing and feed mill manufacture.
By themselves, private investment flows
may not have adequate reach into the poorest regions (often the countryside) of
the poorest countries. Three-quarters of all private money going into the
developing world goes to just a dozen or so favored countries. Official agencies
such as the International Finance Corporation (IFC) of the World Bank and the
U.S. Overseas Private Investment Corporation (OPIC) deserve support from
Congress in their efforts to promote, through inexpensive investment guarantee
programs, increased investment in less favored nations and regions. USAID (or
its successor agency) should join in this effort, learning from these agencies
how it also can design better partnering relationships with the private sector.
None of this stress on partnering
relationships is intended to deny the irreplacability of some more traditional
bilateral or multilateral "government to government" development
cooperation measures. There are some necessary ingredients in the development
process (e.g., rural roads, school systems, irrigation management institutions,
better state policies) that PVOs are not equipped to provide and that private
sector actors have little incentive to provide because these ingredients are,
in their essence, "public" goods. But once these public goods are in
place, development cooperation efforts should concentrate on mobilizing PVO
networks and private sector investments.
The public/private sector partnering
model we are describing here is not the same thing as "tied aid," of
the kind widely used by Japan and long opposed by many in the U.S. assistance
community. Aid given with a "buy American" tie-in is
trade-distorting, and looks too much like corporate welfare. We are, however,
advocating an inclusion of the private sector in U.S. development cooperation
policy strategies.
X. Parallel Trade Policy Responses
If U.S. agriculture is to benefit from
future economic growth abroad, trade policy reforms will also be needed. A
first step should be prompt renewal of "fast track" negotiation
authority. Fast track procedures have been a key to the successful conduct of
U.S. trade policy ever since 1974, when Congress first made them available to
the President. They allow U.S. trade officials to negotiate with credibility
abroad because they specify that any agreement reached will either be approved
or rejected by Congress without amendment (in a single deadline-driven,
limited-debate, up-or-down vote). Without fast track guarantees, foreign
governments will be reluctant to offer any concessions to U.S. trade negotiators,
for fear that Congress will ask for still more concessions after the
"final" international bargain has been struck.
Congress has known for years (ever since
the disastrous Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act of 1930) that it should not attempt to
micro-manage trade policy. And it has known at least since the 1960s (when it
created the semi-independent Office of the U.S. Trade Representative) that it
should not try to micro-manage the conduct of trade negotiations. Unfortunately
Congress seems to have forgotten, since 1994, the importance of allowing
presidents to submit negotiated agreements for ratification on a clean
up-or-down basis. Unless fast track authority is renewed by Congress, the next
round of trade talks will have to be postponed and the significant follow-on
trade expansion opportunities that are now waiting to be captured for U.S.
agriculture will be lost.
The fast track renewal debate has
recently been paralyzed by partisans in Congress catering to groups holding
opposing positions on labor and environment issues. Democratic partisans have
insisted that any renewal of fast track must come with guarantees that future
trade agreements will provide extraordinary protections for labor and the
environment. Republican partisans have insisted that labor and environmental
protection issues should play no role in future trade negotiations. So long as
this paralysis continues, both sides will lose. There will be no new
international protections for labor and the environment, and no new market
opening trade agreements. One attractive escape from this paralysis would be to
renew in 1997 the same kind of fast track authority given to President Bush by
a Democratic Congress in the 1988 Trade Act, authority which is flexible in
that it neither prohibits nor requires labor and environment conditionality.
This bipartisan approach brought results in both NAFTA and the Uruguay Round
and should be considered as a worthy approach to ending the current trade
policy blockage.
While trade negotiators should be
empowered to pursue the goal of opening markets abroad for U.S. farm exports,
USDA officials also have a role to play - often in partnership with the private
sector - in the promotion of those exports. The resources and instruments of
export promotion currently available to the USDA are considerable. USDA is even
accused, on occasion, of operating an export promotion program that is
disproportionately large compared to programs in other sectors, and of
operating programs that violate free market principles, or that provide
undeserved "corporate welfare" benefits to U.S. companies. Our
working group held a range of views on USDA's proper role in export promotion.
A majority believed that most currently used export promotion instruments
should be retained, but most also agreed that some discipline and rebalancing
in the use of those instruments was in order. We would prefer to see budget
dollars spent on real market development programs - especially for high value
products - rather than on the direct subsidization of lower-value bulk
commodities.
Many in our working group believed there
was justification for investing public funds, in partnership with the private
sector, in the development of additional markets for U.S. farm products abroad,
especially high value products. Public support for dietary diversification and
improvement in foreign countries is good for both foreign development and for
U.S. agriculture. Several existing programs (including the Market Access
Program - or MAP - and the Foreign Market Development Cooperator Program - or
FMD) operate in a partnering fashion, build future markets, and deserve to
continue. The objective of these programs is to acquaint potential customers,
especially in high income growth regions such as East Asia, with the full mix of
high value farm products that U.S. producers, processors, and exporters have to
sell. Critics brand these programs as "corporate welfare" (the same
criticism that has been leveled at OPIC), yet claims can also be made for their
success (exports of California wine, promoted through this program, have
increased dramatically over the past ten years). If disciplined and
well-managed these programs they can represent a responsible partnership effort
between the public and the private sector. These programs do not distort trade;
the new Uruguay Round agreement on agriculture recognizes as much by placing
them in the unrestricted "green box"). And the dollar cost to
taxpayers is relatively small. The MAP is currently being funded at less than
$100 million a year.
We are less certain that the taxpayer�s
marginal dollar should be spent on high volume direct export subsidy programs,
such as the Export Enhancement Program (EEP). Most of the benefits of direct
export subsidies are captured not by U.S. farmers, or even by foreign food
consumers, but by foreign governments. Under EEP, foreign governments (for
example, the government of China, or the government of Egypt) can get the U.S.
commodities that they would have purchased anyway at an artificially low price.
And when extra U.S. sales abroad are generated by EEP, the result is not always
good for U.S. producers. In recent years the use of EEP to expand U.S. wheat
sales abroad has brought a perverse result: larger sales of Canadian wheat to
the U.S. We believe it is unfortunate that USDA has historically spent so much
more on EEP than on more genuine market development programs such as MAP and
FMD. Now that direct export subsidy use by competitors such as the EU is
limited under the Uruguay Round agreement, we see an opportunity to stop
stressing direct export subsidies in U.S. farm sales promotion programs.
USDA operates a number of other programs
in the export promotion area which work well, including a small Emerging
Markets Program (EMP) originally authorized in the 1990 farm bill, which
promotes development and exports through sharing of U.S. agricultural sector
expertise, and several international cooperation and development programs, such
as the highly regarded Cochran Fellowship Program (CFP). Since 1984, the CFP has
provided training in the U.S. for more than 4000 agriculturalist participants
from 47 different countries; this training is offered in close association with
USDA agencies, and with private U.S. agricultural trade and market development
associations. Funding is leveraged by utilizing, where possible, PVOs or other
private groups to provide some of the hosting, technical training, and
logistical support for the international trainees. USDA has been able to
document a number of direct benefits to U.S. farm exports from the CFP (wheat
to Slovenia, popcorn to Colombia, soybean products to Bulgaria, and high value
products to Poland, China, Indonesia, and Malaysia), plus the creation of new
business to business contacts and university linkages.
In the area of agricultural trade
promotion, USAID as well as USDA should also seek better ways to partner with
state-level government, farm, or industry group organizations in the U.S. The
professionalism of state-level agencies is much higher today than it was a generation
ago, and in the age of globalization the international focus of these state
agencies has been dramatically enlarged. State organizations are frequently
more innovative, more flexible and responsive, and sometimes even better funded
than federal agencies today. U.S. private sector and PVO organizations are
already deeply connected at the state level, and federal institutions should
find better ways to partner with states as well.
XI. Conclusion
Friends of U.S. agriculture should be
worried about any further diminution of U.S. foreign assistance and trade
expansion efforts abroad. Much of the prosperity of U.S. agriculture today is a
reflection of such efforts in the past. The prosperity of U.S. agriculture in
the future depends heavily upon what we do today.
Three things should be done immediately.
First, we should reverse the recent drop in budget resources allocated to
international development cooperation activities. A reversal of the downward
trend in the 150 account and a restoration of development cooperation resources
within that account should be a bipartisan policy priority in 1997. President
Clinton�s call for an increase in the 150 account for FY 1998 should receive
support from all friends of American agriculture.
Second is a need to reconfigure the
institutions and practices we use in delivering development cooperation
policies abroad. We should have less of some things (less centralized
regulation, less congressional micro-management, and less subordination to
short-term diplomatic concerns), alongside more frequent and more effective
partnering with private companies, PVOs, and multilateral organizations. As
development cooperation resources are being restored, in other words, a larger
share of those resources should be redirected toward partnership activities,
private sector activities (profit and non-profit), and away from ineffective
Cold War era government-to-government budget support programs.
Third is a need to revitalize U.S. trade
expansion activities abroad by breaking the partisan deadlock over renewal of
fast track negotiating authority.
How can policy leaders, particularly in
Congress, be persuaded to support such an agenda for U.S. development
cooperation and trade policy reform in 1997? One key to success will lie in
creating a broad coalition to promote change. This will mean engaging not just
farm and agribusiness organizations; not just U.S. universities and development
PVOs. It will also mean reaching beyond those with a specialized knowledge or
interest in food and agriculture. Population policy, health policy, and
environmental policy leaders should be engaged as well.
But a parallel requirement for success
will be a sustained leadership effort from within the U.S. agricultural
community itself. American agriculture is not only financially strong and
globally engaged. It is also politically sophisticated and well- organized. In
its own self interest it should now invest a larger portion of its own
political energy in the defense of enlightened, reformed, and revitalized U.S.
development cooperation and trade policies abroad.
REFERENCES
Alexandratos, Nikos, ed. 1995. World
Agriculture: Towards 2010, An FAO Study. Published by the Food and
Agriculture Organization of the United Nations. New York: John Wiley &
Sons.
Anderson, Kym. 1987. "Does
Agricultural Growth in Poor Countries Harm Agricultural-Exporting Rich
Countries?" Background paper for address given at the Australian Center
for International Agricultural Research, Canberra, May 14.
Pinstrup-Andersen, Per; Mattias Lundberg,
and James L. Garrett, 1995. Foreign Assistance to Agriculture: A Win-Win
Proposition. Food Policy Report, International Food Policy Research
Institute, Washington, D.C.
Bathrick, David D. 1996.
"Agricultural Development for Global Well Being: Expanded Roles for
Multilateral Development Banks," Washington, D.C.: Chemonics
International, Inc.
Easterbrook, Gregg. January 1997.
"Forgotten Benefactor of Humanity." Atlantic Monthly.
Houck, James. 1987. "Foreign
Agricultural Assistance: It�s Mostly a Good Thing for U.S. Farmers." Choices
(First Quarter), p. 19.
de Janvry, Alain; Elisabeth Sadoulet, and
T. Kelly White, 1989. "Foreign Aid�s Effect on U.S. Farm Exports: Benefits
or Penalties?" Economic Research Service, Foreign Agricultural Economic
Report Number 238, U.S. Department of Agriculture.
Kellogg, Earl, Richard Kodl, and P.
Garcia, 1986. "The Effects of Agricultural Growth on Agricultural Imports
in Developing Countries." American Journal of Agricultural Economics,
Vol. 68, No. 5 (December), pp. 1347-1352.
Lee, John E., Jr., and Matthew Shane.
June 1985. United States Agricultural Interests and Growth in the Developing
Economies: the Critical Linkage. Washington, D.C.: ERS, U.S. Department of
Agriculture.
Lipton, Michael, and Robert Paarlberg.
1990. "The Role of the World Bank in Agricultural Development in the
1990s," Washington, D.C.: International Food Policy Research Institute,
October.
Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Development (OECD). 1996. "Shaping the 21st Century: The Contribution of
Development Cooperation." Paris: OECD.
Ruttan, Vernon H. 1996. U.S.
Development Assistance Policy. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Sek, Lenore, and Charles E. Hanrahan,
1996. "How Is U.S. Agriculture Faring Under NAFTA and the WTO? Proceedings
of a CRS Seminar." CRS Report for Congress, Congressional Research
Service, Library of Congress.
Swaminathan, M.S. 1994. Letter to Environment
Vol. 36, No. 3 (April 1994), pp. 3-4.
U.S. Agency for International
Development, 1986. "Investments in Agriculture." USAID Program and
Operations Assessment Report No. 15, Washington, D.C.
World Bank. 1996 "Rural Development:
From Vision to Action: Summary." October 23, 1996, Draft.